Skip to main content

Allocating budget in developing countries, the need to fight corruption: evidence from Sub-Saharan African countries

Abstract

This paper highlights the need to fight corruption in developing economies to ensure a better allocation of public resources in a context of institutional failure with the discretionary power of budgetary authorities. The study uses a panel of 48 Sub-Saharan African countries by combining several databases (WDI, WGI, SPEED BASE DATA and PWT), estimate by generalized moment method in system, the bias-corrected estimation linear dynamic panel data [6] and the type of error correction (Driscoll–Kraay). The results indicate that the phenomenon of corruption in the form of rent capture has two effects on public resources. One effect is linked to the level of public spending and the other to the distribution of public resources. Thus, corruption leads to an increase in the overall level of public spending. Corruption reduces spending on education, mining and communications, but increases spending on the military, health and transport. The study recommends that political leaders in developing countries strengthen and rigorously enforce anti-corruption laws, and raise public awareness of the underground economy.

Introduction

The management of public resources is hampered by a series of institutional shortcomings that include not only corruption, but also a lack of transparency, a lack of accountability on the part of stakeholders, insufficient public participation and a lack of independence on the part of the bodies that oversee the preparation and execution of the state budget.

In this context of a market economy with competition in developing countries, the relationship between entrepreneurs and public authorities in terms of budget allocation is of particular importance. Insofar as economic actors (multinationals, medium-sized businesses, associations, etc.….) can exert pressure on a government through lobbying [33], policy-makers and bureaucrats can indulge in illicit practices since the latter have discretionary power. In this posture, they no longer act in the interests of society as a whole but capture rents like any other economic actor, which is a form of corruption. The result is preferential treatment linked to corruption and rent-seeking, which can introduce bias into the composition of public spending and the allocation of resources [11]. This rent becomes an issue in public decision-making, and anticipating it encourages interest groups to commit resources to public decision-makers to make it effective. In this sense, rent-seeking corresponds to "the set of activities consisting of the expenditure of scarce resources to capture an artificially created transfer" [32] and is, therefore, the source of a waste of resources, of a social loss, compared to profit-seeking activities which create value [7].

Rent-seeking can be likened to corruption in that certain agents' appropriate rents, thereby transferring collective wealth to these same agents by tampering with the rules of economic activity. This idea, supported by Krueger [23], is generally found in the fraudulent awarding of contracts and the like to suppliers. In this sense, rent-seeking becomes a form of corruption (with or without theft), since the intervention of a corrupter makes it possible to pay a public official to misuse his power and exceed the rules of his office. In the same vein, Dridi [12] and De La Croix and Delavalade [9, 11] argue that corruption affects not only the level but also the distribution of public spending.

The previous work has illuminated the literature on corruption on the one hand and budget allocation on the other, but also on the effects of corruption on public spending. For example, Ngono [26] deals with the problem of corruption, specifically that of politicians seeking employment, and Azam [3] deals with corruption but focuses on its effect on growth in 14 Latin American and Caribbean countries. However, in developing countries, few studies have examined how government efficiency in budget allocation, and particularly rent capture, is perceived as corruption, especially in Sub-Saharan Africa. It should be noted that in Sub-Saharan Africa, corruption is a phenomenon that pervades all areas of the economy. Habib [17] shows that African countries are highly corrupt. In the same vein, Tanzi and Davoodi [31] argue that the total amount of expenditure is artificially inflated by the sums embezzled or bribed when public decision-makers are corrupt, particularly in a "bureaucratic" regime. In the case of corruption in the sense of embezzlement of public funds, the state budget includes not only actual public spending but also the sums embezzled. Moreover, Sahnoun and Abdennadher [29] and Jajkowicz and Droiszova [22] provide empirical evidence that corruption hurts public spending in developing countries.

According to the World Bank's governance index, the control of corruption is very weak, at around −0.25.

As an extension of rent-seeking theory in institutional economics, analyzing the efficiency of governments in allocating budgets and distributing public spending in Sub-Saharan African countries is of prime interest, since these countries are struggling to ensure their development efficiently in a context of transition economies with discretionary administrative power and institutional failure. A public expenditure model is, therefore, used while incorporating corruption as a rent capture phenomenon. A dynamic panel model of 48 Sub-Saharan African countries is estimated using efficient and robust methods, namely: the method of generalized moments in a system (GMM); bias-corrected estimation of linear dynamic panel data models of Breitung et al. [6] and regression with Driscoll–Kraay standard errors. The alternative use of these different dynamic panel methods makes it possible to resolve the problems of endogeneities, multicollinearities and omitted variables to obtain robust results. The study shows that corruption is detrimental to budget management. On the one hand, it inflates the overall level of public investment, and on the other, it affects the composition and allocation of public spending. The results indicate that corruption distorts budget allocation in favor of sectors where the risk of detecting corruption is very low, to the detriment of sectors where it is difficult to extract rent. The rest of the article is divided into three sections. The first section provides a brief review of the literature. The second section deals with the analysis methodology, while the third section presents the results of the estimations and the ensuing discussions.

Literature review

This heading first reviews the existing literature on the subjects of corruption and public investment.

Considered by the World Bank as the abuse of public service for personal enrichment, corruption is a relatively complex phenomenon that encompasses a range of human actions [8]. For Jain [21], corruption broadly refers to practices in which "public officials, legislators and politicians use the powers delegated to them by the community to pursue their economic interests." It includes embezzlement, influence peddling and bribery.

Corruption with and without theft can be clearly distinguished using the agency model developed by Shleifer and Vishny [30]. The model assumes a public good produced by the government and sold at price p. The agent can limit the supply of this good without risk of detection to maximize the sum of bribes resulting from this sale. When the revenue destined for the state ends up in the agent's pocket, there is bribery with theft, since there is theft of public resources. On the other hand, when the agent maximizes the bribes by adding a sum x to the price p of the good, there is corruption without theft. It is, therefore, the user who is subject to theft, not the state. For the user, it is always preferable to deal with bribery with theft, as the actual price may be lower than the price p of bribery without theft [11]. Consequently, corruption distorts not only the allocation of public investment but also the overall level of public spending.

By using their discretionary power in allocating the budget, public authorities can redirect resources toward sectors where they have greater scope for extracting rents. Similarly, Mauro [25] provides empirical evidence that for a high preference for bribes, public authorities are likely to invest in projects that offer the best rent-seeking opportunities. Indeed, these types of expenditure may involve high-tech goods produced by oligopolistic markets, corruption being difficult to detect since the prices of high-tech products are not comparable to the prices of innovative products. In this respect, Gupta et al. [14] have recently shown that corruption reduces the amount spent on education and health, as it is difficult to obtain bribes compared to other sectors of activity. These situations offer politicians and bureaucrats more advantageous bribes thanks to higher profits. In addition, Bardhan [4] argues that rent-seeking by senior officials and policy-makers can lead to a redirection of resources toward spending on large projects. For him, project size is a bottom-up function of the cost of purchased goods. Furthermore, Tanzi and Davoodi [31] show that, given budgetary constraints, corruption redirects public investment toward large projects and effectively leads to an increase in project size and complexity, to the detriment of expenditure categories such as operation and maintenance, education and health. They base their analysis on the famous "golden rule." This idea is widely shared by Mauro [24]. Considering Barro's (1990) model, in which public spending includes public goods (services), Babar (2011) shows that in the presence of corruption, public goods are at a much lower level than in the absence of corruption. He shows that corrupt officials and bureaucrats steal part of the resources that would normally increase the supply of public goods.

For his part, Zohal (2010) uses an endogenous rent-seeking model to demonstrate that corruption has an impact on the distribution of public spending. At the equilibrium point, he finds that corruption increases the amount of public spending on health. In his view, corruption is, therefore, a factor that stimulates spending on human capital, particularly in the health sector. In the same vein, some authors have developed models to support the idea that corruption is a lubricant. These include Huntington (1668), Leff (1964) and Theobald (1990). They argue that, in the absence of institutional capital (effective institutions and systems of governance) with a high level of regulation, corruption compensates for institutional weaknesses and the effects of heavy bureaucracy while stimulating the economy. Beck and Maher (1986), in turn, argue that corruption can allocate investment at its most efficient level since the highest bribes are paid by the most efficient entrepreneurs. The latter find that corruption compensates for public rigidities.

Delavallade [10], De la Croix and Delavallade [9] and Mauro [25] have also demonstrated, using empirical data, that corruption negatively affects investment in public human capital (health and education), but positively affects certain expenditures, notably military expenses, fuel, energy, public transport and so on. Using a dynamical corruption model, De la Croix and Delavallade [10] show that corruption negatively affects government spending on human capital. Their study covered 63 countries observed over the period 1996–2004, using the triple least squares (3LS) method with instrumental variables.

Data and analysis methodology

Theoretical analytical approach

Justifying the theoretical background of the model is a prerequisite for specifying the empirical model.

Following Delavallade [9] and Hessami [18], we include the corruption parameter in public spending and consider the basic framework of an economy, i.e., a concentration of identical agents whose measure is unitary and whose have a lifetime between 0 and infinity. Given that utility is maximized, the agent has the choice of working (in the rentier sector or the productive sector). Thus, \(1-{x}_{t}\) is the number of people who have made a priesthood and decided to join the manufacturing sector. People looking for an annuity represent \({x}_{t}\)

In the model, it is assumed that no sector is exempt from corruption as a result of over-invoicing and fraudulently obtaining public contracts.

To grasp the induced effect of corruption on public service, we analyze the lines of Hussain [20]. For him, as a corrupt bureaucrat takes a share of expenditure for a social cause, the level of service diminishes at the same time. Thus, when bureaucrats are all honest, no corruption exists, and the level of public service provided by the government is given by:

$$G_{1} = ng$$
(1)

On the opposite, if a bureaucrat decides to take a share of public resources θ, the level of service provided is as follows:

$$G_{2} = \left( {1 - \vartheta \theta } \right)ng$$
(2)

with \(0<\theta <1\).

As we observe \({G}_{1}>{G}_{2}\), means that the level of public service without corruption is much higher than the level without corruption.

Furthermore, if resources are diverted as a result of overcharging or rent-seeking, decision-makers anticipate an initial level \({G}_{1}\) high level of public spending which will be higher than the level invested G2. In this case, we always G1 > G2. Equation (2) also shows the effect of corruption on public spending.

Select variables, source and expected signs

Variables were selected mainly on a literature basis. The discretionary behavior of bureaucrats is a source of distortion in the production and provision of government agencies. In addition to influencing overall expenditure, corruption also affects the structure of public spending [11, 16, 25].

Beyond the corrupt phenomenon, certain variables are likely to influence the level of allocation of public spending. Such variables make it possible to better control the effects of the institutional environment on budget allocations. GDP per capita growth rate is used as a proxy to measure a country's level of economic development. The more resources a country has, all other things being equal, the more it can increase public investment in some sectors [11, 15, 24, 25].

The rate of population growth is likely to affect the level of public spending since it increases the demand for public services: Investment in health and education is expected to be influenced by the rate of population growth. This variable was also used by Delavallade [11] in his thesis. Mauro [25] also shows that educational expenditure is likely to increase with the share of the population aged less than 15. This is expected to have a positive sign. The level of public investment can be boosted by the level of inflation. This is because the high rising cost of living leads to an appreciation in the price of goods, which, in turn, increases the level of public investment. A positive effect is expected. The level of government spending in a past period is also used to explain the current level of government expenditures. The level of spending in year t-1 can explain the level of spending in year t.

Empirical data analysis

To carry out our estimations, we first carry out a variable descriptive analysis, then we specify the model to be estimated, and finally, we justify the estimation procedure.

Statistical analysis of model variables and variable sources

Table 1 provides a statistical description of the model variables. The analysis shows that in Sub-Saharan Africa, the average level of corruption is approaching 3, with little disparity between countries. Government spending on the health sector has an average of 2.3381, with little disparity between countries. In the cases of investment in education and defense, the median is higher than that for health, but the divergence is far from that of the health sector. As far as other expenditure is concerned, it should be noted that it varies widely. There is considerable variation between countries.

Table 1 Statistiques descriptives des variables et sources

Econometric specification

As the allocation of public resources is left to the discretion of public decision-makers and bureaucrats, we estimate the effects of public action efficiency in this allocation of public resources. As we already know from the literature that public resource allocation is subject to a corruption bias, depending on the weight of rent, we estimate the effect of corruption in this allocation.

To achieve this, we specify a model inspired by [11]. The result is Eq. 3

, which is estimated by introducing sectoral expenses one by one.

$$\left( {\frac{{dep_{{\sec_{s} }} }}{pib}} \right)_{it} = \alpha_{0} + \alpha_{1} \left( {\frac{{dep_{{\sec_{s} }} }}{pib}} \right)_{it - 1} + \alpha_{2} corrup_{it} + \theta X_{it} + \varepsilon_{{{\text{it}}}}$$
(3)

In this equation, \((\frac{de{p}_{{\mathit{sec}}_{s}}}{pib}{)}_{it}\), it is the amount of spending in a given sector as just one percentage of GDP. Sectors covered include health, education, defense, transport, communications, energy, fuels and mining. corrup_it is the level of corruption in each country. The share of spending in a given sector as a percentage of GDP lagged one period is denoted by the term \((\frac{de{p}_{{\mathit{sec}}_{s}}}{pib}{)}_{it-1}\). The vector \({X}_{it}\) denotes a set of control variables. As for the effect of corruption on resource allocation, it is captured by the coefficient \({\alpha }_{2}\)

We can also analyze the effect of corruption on the level of public spending on human capital as a percentage of public spending. To do this, we try to capture the effect of corruption on the level of public expenditure as a percentage of GDP. We, therefore, obtain the following Eq. 4:

$$\left( {\frac{{dep_{tot} }}{pib}} \right)_{it} = \varphi_{0} + \varphi_{1} \left( {\frac{{dep_{tot} }}{pib}} \right)_{it - 1} + \varphi_{2} corrup_{it} + \phi X_{it} + \varepsilon_{it}$$
(4)

with \((\frac{dep\_tot}{pib}{)}_{it}\), total expenditure as a percentage of GDP.

It is recognized that:

$$\frac{{dep\_\sec t_{i} }}{pib} = \frac{dep - tot}{{pib}}*\frac{{dep\_\sec_{i} }}{dep\_tot}$$
(5)

From Eq. (5), we can determine the effect of corruption on the level of public spending as a percentage of total spending using the term \({\alpha }_{2}/{\varphi }_{2}\).

We, therefore, analyze in greater detail the effects of corruption on the allocation of public resources.

To achieve this objective, an appropriate estimation strategy is needed to obtain better results.

Estimating strategy

The method used in this study is the generalized method of moments in a system (GMM system). This method was first proposed by Arellano and Bond [2] and Holtz-Eakin Newey and Rosen [19]. Two estimators are derived from this method: the difference MMG estimator or Arrellano and Bond [2] and the MMG estimator of Blundell and Bond [5] or system MMG estimator. This technique offers enormous advantages in terms of estimation, particularly for macroeconomic data, which are generally associated with endogeneity problems.

In this model, we include the lagged dependent variable as an explanatory variable. The introduction of this variable creates an endogeneity problem. Moreover, the use of institutional variables is also a source of endogeneity, given how they are calculated. Institutional variables are produced from expert opinion and survey data, and are, therefore, potentially subject to measurement error [1, 34].

The first-difference model, or Arellano and Bond [2], involves taking the first-difference of the equation to be estimated for each period, in order to eliminate country-specific effects, and then instrumenting the explanatory variables of the first-difference equation with their level values lagged by at least one period or more. Although this method is more powerful than OLS, instrumenting with level-lagged variables does not seem appropriate and does not allow us to identify the influence of time-invariant factors. Blundell and Bond's system MMG estimator combines first-difference with at least one period lagged level equations. The latter are more appropriate than the former. Indeed, Monte Carlo simulations by Blundell and Bond [5] have shown that the system MMG compares favorably with the first-difference estimator. They argued that, when the instrumentation is small, the parameters are biased for small samples. But combining first-difference equations with level equations, and estimating them simultaneously, increases the importance of estimator precision when the explanatory variables are highly cross-correlated.

Several preconditions must, therefore, be met before MMG can be used in the system. For Roodman [27, 28], it makes sense for the study period \((T)\) to be significantly reduced compared to the sample size of the study \((N)\,\).

In this study, N is 48 and T = 23. Two tests are associated with the MMG estimator in a dynamic system to ensure the robustness of the results. These are the Sargan/Hansen over-identification test, which verifies the validity of lagged variables as instruments, and the Arellano and Bond autocorrelation test, where the zero hypothesis is the non-existence of first-order autocorrelation of errors in the level equation.

To ensure the stability of the results, two other dynamic panel methods are used: the bias-corrected estimation of linear dynamic panel data models by Breitung et al. [6] and regression with Driscoll–Kraay with standard errors.

Driscoll–Kraay standard errors are robust to very general forms of spatial and temporal dependence when the temporal dimension becomes important. This non-parametric technique for generating standard errors imposes no restrictions on the limiting behavior of the number of panels. Consequently, the size of the cross-sectional dimension in finite samples is not a constraint on feasibility—even if the number of panels is much larger than T. However, it should be noted that the estimator is based on asymptotics of large T. Some caution is, therefore, called for. Therefore, some caution should be exercised when applying this estimator to panel data sets with a large number of panels but a small number of observations over time.

For the bias-corrected estimation of models of linear dynamic panel data from Breitung et al. [6], this is an estimator based on a simple set of moment conditions which can be easily solved using standard numerical optimization procedures. It is easy to generalize the estimator to higher order auto-regressive models or to random effects dynamic models. An estimator of the asymptotic covariance matrix is readily accessible, as is robust standard errors that efficiently adjust for cross-sectional dependence, an important feature in panel macroeconomic analysis.

Findings and comments

The results show that corruption not only increases the overall level of public expenditures, but also distorts the allocation of public resources between different sectors of activity. Post-estimation tests show that the results are valid and robust to alternative estimation methods. Indeed, it favors certain sectors to the detriment of others. Corruption positively affects the share of public funds allocated to health, the army, fuel and energy and transport on the one extreme, and on the other, but negatively affects the share of resources allocated to education, communication and mining. It should be noted that the results are significant, of the order of 1% for the defense sector, 10% for health and 5% for energy and transport. Indeed, a 1% increase in the level of public corruption leads to a 0.386% increase in health-care spending. This result can be easily interpreted as the purchase of certain imported materials, the net costs of which are difficult to verify, and other large-scale projects in the health field. In the defense sector, a 1% increase in corruption leads to a respective increase of 0.928% in military expenses, 0.1365% in energy expenses and 0.0235% in transportation expenses. It should be noted that the purchase of combat equipment and investigations remains the least controlled areas due to the sensitivity of information and confidentiality, and it is easy to extract rents. The results show that a 1% increase in corruption leads to a drop in public spending in certain areas. In fact, these are sectors where the risk of corruption being detected is very high, and rents are difficult to extract. These include education, down 1.222%, communications, down 0.0377%, and mining, down 0.0894%. Delavallade [10] found a similarly similar result for 64 countries over the period 1964–2001, using triple least squares (3LS).

Aside from the distorted budget allocation, the last column of Table 2 highlights the fact that corruption significantly inflates global spending levels in Sub-Saharan African countries. A 1% rise in corruption leads to a 2.349% boost in total spending. This increase in public expenditure is due to the over-invoicing of certain imported products and others that genuinely escape the price control mechanism. It may also result from the deliberate intention of rent-seeking decision-makers in that the misappropriation of public funds, the state budget includes not only actual public expenditure but also the sums embezzled. This result is confirmed by the work of Tanzi and Davoodi [31], who show that the total amount of expenditure is artificially inflated by the sums embezzled or bribed when public decision-makers are corrupt, particularly in a “bureaucratic” regime.

Examination of the results indicates that the sectors in which corruption negatively impacts the share of the budget allocated to them appear to be the less rent-producing sectors. Nevertheless, those that benefit from budgetary favors are those in which resources are easily concealed, either through the awarding or execution of public contracts, or through the provision of working materials. In developing countries in general, and in the emerging economies of Sub-Saharan Africa in particular, certain areas are fertile ground for rent-seeking. Indeed, the transport, military and health sectors, as well as the fuel and energy industries, seem to be ideal for corruption, since the risk of detection remains minimal. For Hessami [18], these types of sectors where corruption increases public spending are those where rent-seeking is more secretive and where auditing is extremely difficult to detect over-invoicing and fraudulent awarding of large contracts. On the other hand, sectors such as education, communication and mining present high risks of detection, as these sectors are much more involved in operating with small projects.

Our findings are compatible with those obtained by De la Croix and Delavallade [9, 11] on 63 countries with biennial data from 1996 to 2004. Using a dynamic corruption model estimated by triple least squares with endogenization of graft, they show that public investment is distorted in favor of certain rent-seeking expenditures. Indeed, a 1% increase in corruption leads to a decrease of more than 1% in public spending on education in Sub-Saharan African countries. In contrast with the education sector, in the health sector, a 0.386% increase in public spending is caused by a 1% increase in corruption. This result is in phase with that of Gupta et al. [16] and is contrary to that found by De la Croix and Delavallade [11]. For the latter, the health sector is not subject to corruption and, therefore, does not benefit from large budgets and projects. However, in Sub-Saharan Africa, corruption seems to be rampant in the health sector, where even access to certain health services is conditional on bribes. The case of the coronavirus and many other pandemics are a perfect illustration of this, as the importation of certain equipment generates rents. This distortion in the allocation of public resources to education can be explained by the fact that in SSA countries, there are no major public projects in favor of education, and this sector is highly vulnerable to corruption. Furthermore, investment in education does not seem to be used effectively. This is why, in December 2018, the World Bank adopted an Education Development Project calls on the governments of African countries, particularly those in Sub-Saharan Africa, to invest effectively and massively in education, training for their populations and health.

The results of the estimates of the effects of corruption on the share of public expenditure in %GDP are shown in Table 2.

Table 2 Results of corruption impact estimates in %GDP (GMM in system)

Conclusion and economic policy implications

The aim of this study was to analyze the role of the institutional environment in budget execution in developing countries. In particular, the role of corruption in the allocation of public resources is analyzed, highlighting the discretionary power of the budgetary authority. To this end, data from several sources were estimated in a panel of 48 Sub-Saharan African (SSA) countries using sophisticated methods, namely, the generalized method of moments, bias-corrected estimation linear dynamic panel dada [6] and type error correction [13].

The results indicate that corruption is detrimental to the allocation of public resources, as it inflates the level of public expenses and distorts the distribution of the budget. The study reveals that corruption creates a distortion in resource allocation that favors sectors where resources are easily concealed (defense, transport and health) to the detriment of those where control over the use of funds is easier (education and mining).

In terms of economic policy, political decision-makers need to strengthen budgetary control and anti-corruption laws throughout the economic sphere.

And it fosters the business environment by combating corruption in the awarding of public contracts, in order to attract foreign investors wishing to invest in a given field (Tables 3, 4, 5 and 6).

Table 3 Estimating the effects of corruption on the share of expenditure as a % of GDP [6]
Table 4 Results of estimates of the effects of corrupt practices on the share of expenditure in % of expenditure [6]
Table 5 Results of estimates of the effects of corruption on the share of expenditure in %GDP [13]
Table 6 Results of estimates of the effects of corruption on the share of expenditure as % expenditure Drisc/Kraay [13]

Availability of data and materials

https://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/Home/Reports. http://wdi.worldbank.org/. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.15141/S5Q94M. https://zenodo.org/record/46822#.VvFcNWMvyjp.

Abbreviations

SSA:

Sub-Saharan African

GMM:

Generalized moments method

OECD:

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development

WHO:

World Health Organization

References

  1. Acemoglu D, Johnson S, Robinson JA (2001) The colonial origins of comparative development: an empirical investigation. Am Econ Rev 91(5):1369–1401

  2. Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58(2):277–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Azam M (2022) Governance and economic growth: evidence from 14 Latin America and Caribbean countries. J Knowl Econ 13(2):1470–1495. https://doi.org/10.1007/s13132-021-00781-2

  4. Bardhan P (1997) Corruption and development: a review of issues. J Econ Literature 35(3):1320–1346

    Google Scholar 

  5. Blundell R, Bond S (1998) Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. J Econom 87(1):115–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Breitung J, Kripfganz S, Hayakawa K (2022) Bias-corrected method of moments estimators for dynamic panel data models. Econ Stat 24:116–132. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecosta.2021.07.001

  7. Buchanan JM, Tollison RD, Tullock G (1980) Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society. Texas A & M University. http://www.gbv.de/dms/zbw/02063613X.pdf

  8. D’Agostino G, Dunne JP, Pieroni L (2016) Government spending, corruption and economic growth. World Dev 84:190–205

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. De la Croix D, Delavallade C (2009) Corruption and the optimal allocation of public investment. Econ Rev 58(3):637–647

    Google Scholar 

  10. Delavallade C (2006) Corruption and distribution of public spending in developing countries. J Econ Finance 30(2):222–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Delavallade C (2007) Public corruption. Institutional Factors and Effects on Public Spending, 294

  12. Dridi M (2014) Corruption and education: empirical evidence. Int J Econ Financ Issues 4(3):476

    Google Scholar 

  13. Driscoll J, Kraay A (1998) Consistent covariance matrix estimation with spatially dependent panel data. Rev Econ Stat 80(4):549–560

  14. Gupta S, Sharan R, de Mello L (2000) Corruption and military spending. In: IMF working papers 00/23; International Monetary Fund

  15. Gupta S, Abed GT, Stafaf IMF (2001) Governance, corruption, and economic performance. International Monetary Fund

  16. Gupta S, Davoodi H, Alonso-Terme R (2002) Does corruption affect income inequality and poverty? Econ Governance 3(1):23–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Habib S, Abdelmonen S, Khaled M (2020) The effect of corruption on the environmental quality in African Countries: a panel quantile regression analysis. J Knowl Econ 11:788–804

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Hessami Z (2010) Corruption and the composition of public expenditures: evidence from OECD Countries, 31

  19. Holtz-Eakin D, Newey W, Rosen HS (1988) Estimating vector autoregressions with panel data. Econometrica 56(6):1371–1395

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Hussain B (2011) Essays on human capital, institutions and economic growth. University of Manchester

  21. Jain AK (2001) Corruption: a review. J Econ Surv 15:71–121. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-6419.00133

  22. Jajkowicz O, Drobiszová A (2015) The effect of corruption on government expenditure allocation in OECD Countries. Acta Univ Agric et Silvic Mendelianae Brun 63(4):1251–1259

  23. Krueger AO (2008) The political economy of the rent-seeking society. In: Congleton RD, Konrad KA, Hillman AL (eds) 40 Years of research on rent seeking 2. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg, pp 151–163. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-79247-5_8

  24. Mauro P (1995) Corruption and growth. Q J Econ 110(3):681–712

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Mauro P (1998) Corruption and the composition of government expenditure. J Public Econ 69(2):263–279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Ngono JFL (2022) Corrupting politicians to get out of unemployment: empirical evidence from Africa. J Knowl Econ

  27. Roodman D (2009) A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bull Econ Stat 71(1):135–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Roodman D (2009) How to do Xtabond2: an introduction to difference and the GMM system in Stata. Stand Genomic Sci 9(1):86–136

    Google Scholar 

  29. Sahnoun M, Abdennadher C (2022) Returns to investment in education in the OECD Countries : does governance quality matter? J Know Econ 13:1819–1842

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Shleifer A, Vishny RW (1993) Corruption. Quart J Econ 108(3):599–617. https://doi.org/10.2307/2118402

  31. Tanzi V, Davoodi H (1997) Corruption, public investment, and growth. In: IMF working papers 97/139; International Monetary Fund

  32. Tollison RD (1982) Rent seeking: a survey. Kyklos 35(4):575‑602. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6435.1982.tb00174.x

  33. Tullock G (1983) Economics of income redistribution. Springer, Netherlands. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-015-7253-8

  34. Williams A, Siddique A (2008) The use (and abuse) of governance indicators in economics: a review. Econ Governance 9(2):131–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Not applicable.

Funding

Not applicable.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

BP ensured the writing of the body of work and formatting. TN conducted the data collection and analysis. MEHW provided analysis and interpretation of results.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Porto Bazie.

Ethics declarations

Ethics approval and consent to participate

Not applicable.

Consent for publication

The authors hereby give their consent for the publication of this article.

Competing interests

There are no competing interests among the authors.

Appendix

Appendix

See Fig. 1.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Stylized facts: correlation between corruption and various human capital indicators and some public spending. a Correlation corruption_military spending. b Correlation corruption_communication spending. c Correlation corruption/education spending. d Correlation corruption/health spending. e Correlation corruption/fuel spending. f Correlation corruption/transport spending. g Correlation corruption mine spending

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bazie, P., Thiombiano, N. & Maiga, E.W.H. Allocating budget in developing countries, the need to fight corruption: evidence from Sub-Saharan African countries. Futur Bus J 10, 2 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1186/s43093-023-00289-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s43093-023-00289-y

Keywords

JEL Classification