Skip to main content

Table 1 Preliminary test results

From: Economic policy uncertainty and stock returns among OPEC members: evidence from feasible quasi-generalized least squares

Country

Start date

Summary statistics

Unit root test

Persistence and endogeneity tests

Mean

SD

Skewness

Kurtosis

Level

First difference

Persistence

Endogeneity

EPU

7-Jan

134.288

45.919

0.89

3.777

− 3.744b***

Stock returns

 Algeria

7-Jan

1.012

0.12

11.061

129.188

− 12.78a***

0.844***

0.024

 Ecuador

12-Feb

1.004

0.021

0.313

3.406

− 9.104a***

0.804***

− 0.021*

 Iran

7-Jan

1.078

0.752

11.526

136.747

− 10.77a***

0.844***

− 0.066

 Iraq

9-Sep

1.099

1.12

10.347

108.39

− 9.962b***

0.791***

− 0.102

 Kuwait

7-Jan

0.996

0.051

− 0.905

6.416

− 6.117a***

0.787***

− 0.024

 Nigeria

7-Jan

1.002

0.075

0.391

8.94

− 5.771a***

0.844***

− 0.067**

 S. Arabia

7-Jan

1.002

0.0671

− 0.25

4.724

− 10.75b***

0.844***

− 0.038

 UAE

7-Jan

1.005

0.055

− 0.035

4.83

− 6.262b***

0.844***

0.011

 Venezuela

7-Jan

1.163

0.486

4.546

29.7

− 1.74a*

0.844***

− 0.075

  1. The null hypothesis for the autocorrelation is there is no serial dependence, while for heteroscedasticity is that there is no conditional heteroscedasticity. The persistence test is conducted by regressing a first-order autoregressive process for the predictor e.g. \(z_{t} = \varphi + \sigma z_{t - 1} + v_{t}\) using OLS estimator. The first order autocorrelation coefficient (σ) captures the persistence effect and is reported in Table 1. The null hypothesis is that there is no persistence effect in the predictor, while the alternative is that there is persistence effect in the predictor. For endogeneity, it involves a three-step procedure. Firstly, we run the following predictive model:: \(s_{t} = \alpha + \beta g_{t - 1} + \varepsilon_{t}\), where \(s_{t}\) is the stock returns and \(g_{t - 1}\) the natural log of global economic policy uncertainty. The second step is that we follow the Westerlund and Narayan [26] by modeling the predictor as follows: \(g_{t}\) = \(\mu \left( {1 - \rho } \right) + \rho g_{t - 1} + v_{t}\) and in the final step, the nexus between the error terms is captured using the following regression: \(\varepsilon_{t} = \gamma v_{t} + \pi_{t}\). If the coefficient \(\gamma\) is statistically different from zero at any of the conventional levels of significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% respectively, then the predictor variable is endogenous; otherwise, it is not. a and b respectively denote models with intercept only and intercept and trend. ***, ** and * represent significance at 1%, 5% and 10% critical levels, respectively.